Self Help

Modern Monopolies - Alex Moazed

Author Photo

Matheus Puppe

· 43 min read

“If you liked the book, you can purchase it using the links in the description below. By buying through these links, you contribute to the blog without paying any extra, as we receive a small commission. This helps us bring more quality content to you!”

BOOK LINK:

CLICK HERE

Here is a summary of the key points from the introduction of Modern Monopolies:

  • Nokia was once a dominant mobile phone manufacturer, but struggled to adapt when Apple’s iPhone and Google’s Android platform disrupted the industry.

  • In 2011, Nokia’s new CEO Stephen Elop issued a “burning platform” memo likening Nokia’s situation to a man trapped on a burning oil platform. He argued Nokia needed to change course urgently.

  • Elop recognized that Nokia was failing to compete on software and ecosystems rather than just device features and specs. Apple and Google had built powerful platforms connecting consumers and developers.

  • Despite changes in strategy, Nokia continued to decline and ended up selling its mobile phone business to Microsoft in 2013, a major failure for the once-dominant company.

  • Nokia’s experience reflects larger shifts underway in many industries, with even giant companies rising and falling rapidly due to technology disruption and platform economics.

  • The book argues we are in a historic period of corporate upheaval, where company lifespans are far shorter than in the past. This creates risks for existing businesses but also opportunities.

  • The authors aim to explain the forces driving this change and how companies can capitalize on platform strategies rather than become victims of disruption.

Nokia failed to see the radical transformation in business and technology over the decade leading up to its demise. This allowed Apple and Google to surpass it with their platform business models that connect consumers and producers. Platforms like iOS, Android, Uber, and Airbnb created new markets and grew rapidly in a way that was impossible until recently.

Platform businesses now dominate the economy. Enabled by technology, they are revolutionizing how we work and connect, just as the industrial revolution did with the assembly line. Nokia clung to a traditional product focus rather than adopting a platform model, leading to its downfall.

Similarly, Blackberry dominated smartphones with its focus on batteries, keyboards, and security. But it dismissed the iPhone, confident that businesses would never switch from Blackberry’s security. However, Blackberry failed to see that the operating system and app developers were key to controlling the market. It thought like a product company when Apple and Google adopted platform strategies. This allowed iOS and Android to surpass Blackberry.

The lesson is that platforms now win in business. Both Nokia and Blackberry provide cautionary tales of how product companies failed to transition to platforms and suffered as a result.

  • RIM initially dismissed the iPhone, thinking its core business customers would stick with BlackBerry. But individuals started demanding iPhones, forcing businesses to support them.

  • Google then launched Android in 2007, positioning it as an open alternative to Apple’s closed system. This established a powerful platform for developers and hardware partners.

  • RIM responded by doubling down on its aging BlackBerry operating system and proprietary approach. But Apple allowing 3rd party apps on the iPhone via the App Store was a game changer.

  • The App Store incentivized developers to build for iPhone over other platforms. BlackBerry’s OS was difficult to develop for and its App World opened too late.

  • RIM failed to transition to a platform model and compete with Apple and Google’s ecosystems. BlackBerry devices like the Storm could not compete with the thriving app communities on iOS and Android.

  • By 2010, RIM’s leaders still didn’t understand the platform dynamics, believing BlackBerry could win with its browser vs. apps. But their defensive strategy focused on enterprise security proved wildly insufficient.

  • Platform businesses like Apple, Facebook, Twitter, LinkedIn, Google, Amazon, etc are dominating the internet and the economy, not just traditional software companies.

  • Marc Andreessen coined the phrase “software is eating the world” in 2011, but platforms are actually what’s eating the world.

  • Platforms leverage network effects and operate differently than traditional businesses. They are becoming modern monopolies.

  • Platforms now dominate the internet - 25% of web traffic is Facebook, 40% disappeared when Google went down once. The top 10 trafficked U.S. websites are platforms.

  • Platforms play an even bigger role in developing countries like China where Alibaba and Tencent dominate e-commerce and social media.

  • In the past, businesses just added software for efficiency gains. Now platforms are completely changing business models.

  • Some traditional businesses like Blockbuster and Borders have already been overtaken by platform competitors like Netflix and Amazon.

  • The book will explain what platforms are, why they are reinventing the economy, and how to build and grow a successful platform business.

  • Platform businesses like Tencent and Baidu dominate China’s internet landscape and economy. Alibaba controls 80% of e-commerce through its Taobao and Tmall platforms.

  • Platforms shape today’s internet and economy. To succeed online you need to understand how platforms work.

  • Pets.com epitomized the failed dot-com business model - grow big fast without a profitable model. It went bankrupt 9 months after its IPO.

  • eBay succeeded where Pets.com failed by having a better business model. It created an online marketplace and grew profitably.

  • Linear business models dominated industry historically - companies like GM and Walmart created and sold products directly to consumers.

  • Platform business models are different - they create ecosystems for interactions between different groups, facilitating the exchange of value.

  • The internet enabled new platform models like eBay’s marketplace. Platforms outcompete linear businesses by leveraging network effects.

Here are the key points from the passage:

  • Traditional companies have operated using supply chains - linear systems for creating and distributing products/services from company to customer. Supply chains enabled efficient mass production and distribution in the 20th century.

  • Platform businesses work differently - they connect networks of consumers and producers to exchange value. Platforms don’t own resources, but provide infrastructure to enable exchanges between users.

  • eBay was an early platform success. Rather than owning inventory, it connected buyers and sellers through its marketplace. This benefitted both groups by enabling global exchanges.

  • eBay was highly profitable because it didn’t have the costs of traditional retailers. It succeeded by harnessing the potential of the internet to connect distributed networks.

In summary, the passage contrasts linear supply chains with platform networks, using eBay as an example of an early platform that connected buyers and sellers globally to exchange goods in a highly profitable way.

  • Platform business models have become incredibly influential, with companies like eBay, Uber, Airbnb, and Apple as prime examples.

  • A platform facilitates exchanges of value between different groups, like consumers and producers. Platforms harness large networks of users and resources.

  • Platforms connect users and allow transactions, creating markets and communities. They don’t own inventory like linear businesses.

  • Platforms grow exponentially while linear models grow linearly. Platforms are more cost-effective and higher scale.

  • “Platform” refers to a business model, not just a piece of technology. Many startups misuse the term.

  • Linux and open source software enabled the development of platforms. Linus Torvalds pioneered new approaches like distributed version control.

  • Platforms have grown rapidly in recent years. While individual companies come and go, platforms are here to stay as the dominant business model.

GitHub provides a platform for software developers to collaborate on code. It makes open source software development easier by hosting code repositories and allowing developers to contribute changes through a user friendly interface. Key points:

  • Linux creator Linus Torvalds originally used a centralized version control system where he was the gatekeeper for changes. As Linux grew, this wasn’t scalable.

  • In 2005, Torvalds created the decentralized version control system Git to better manage contributions to Linux. However, Git was still complex to use from the command line.

  • GitHub, created in 2007, made Git easier to use by adding a graphical user interface. It also added social features to connect developers.

  • GitHub hosts public code repositories for free, allowing anyone to view and contribute to open source projects. Private repositories are available for a fee.

  • GitHub reduces the transaction costs/pain points associated with collaborating on software development. It makes it easy to find projects, contribute changes, and track updates.

  • Like other platforms, GitHub provides infrastructure to facilitate the creation of complements - in this case, code repositories. The more repositories, the more value for the platform.

Platforms create value by facilitating transactions between users. The core transaction is the main way a platform generates value. Platforms perform four key functions: building an audience, enabling matchmaking between users, providing core tools and services, and setting rules and standards.

There are two main types of platforms: exchange platforms and maker platforms. Exchange platforms optimize exchanges between consumers and producers, like Uber connecting drivers and riders. Maker platforms enable producers to create and distribute content to a broad audience, like YouTube.

Exchange platforms have a 1:1 or 1:few matching intention, where a producer can only serve a limited number of consumers at once. Maker platforms have a 1:many matching intention, where content can be consumed by a large unlimited audience.

There are different platform types based on the type of value exchanged, like services marketplaces, product marketplaces, and content platforms. Platforms also exist along a spectrum from commoditized to differentiated based on the complexity of their transactions. More commoditized platforms have simpler transactions with fewer variables that matter to users.

  • Technology shapes our reality and economy in profound ways, not just a means to an end. Examples include the locomotive expanding the definition of “local” and enabling new businesses.

  • Technological change is often gradual, like the Industrial Revolution spanning decades. The full implications take time to play out.

  • Many organizations continue with old business strategy ideas despite technological changes empowering consumers.

  • The ideas behind business strategy were treated as immutable laws for much of the 20th century.

  • Hayek argued we can’t predict the future as economic knowledge is dispersed. Things like Uber emerge that no one could have predicted.

  • Top-down economic planning fails as centralized controllers can’t access all the dispersed knowledge.

  • Platforms are bottom-up systems that allow decentralized individuals to create value, unlocking dispersed knowledge.

  • Platforms like Uber emerge from individual users and producers, not centralized planning. They represent a shift to bottom-up systems.

  • The 20th century mindset of top-down businesses controlling consumers is being displaced by platforms unlocking value from independent users.

  • The practice of “showrooming” - examining a product in a store before buying it cheaper online - allows consumers to find better, less expensive products.

  • Online reviews and recommendations from thousands of “friends” give consumers more power. They can publicly complain if something goes wrong.

  • This shifts power from local stores to consumers, who now have far more information and options. It changes how businesses must operate.

  • Technology enabled this shift, but technology itself is not the sole driver. Human actions shape how technology develops and is used.

  • Platform businesses are harnessing these technological changes in ways that alter basic economic realities and business strategy conventions.

  • The rise of platforms warrants examining the interaction between technology, economics, and society. It challenges long-held economic assumptions.

  • The argument for efficient markets assumes “perfect information.” But perfect information means markets and central planning are equally efficient.

  • In reality, information is imperfect. Hayek argued that centralized planning fails because circumstances constantly change.

  • Decentralized local knowledge is needed for good decisions. The price system aggregates this local knowledge.

  • Technology now allows decentralized coordination of economic activity, challenging traditional strategy.

  • Hayek argued that the price system acts as a “primitive calculator” that allows individual producers to understand economic conditions far away, aggregating local knowledge into overall market prices. This decentralized coordination works better than centralized planning.

  • Coase noted that firms exist to minimize transaction costs of using the market. Firms internally plan some activities when it is more efficient than using the external market.

  • Henderson observed that production costs fall rapidly with economies of scale as firms grow. Larger firms have cost advantages.

  • Porter’s value chain concept broke down firms into components to analyze sources of competitive advantage in each. The goal was optimizing the firm’s set of activities to maximize value.

  • However, coordination costs eventually limit firm growth, resulting in a U-shaped cost curve. This demonstrates the limits of scale that Hayek identified.

  • Lange argued that computers could replace markets for economic coordination, allowing central planning to work. But so far markets have proven more adaptable than centralized systems.

  • In 1965, economist Oscar Lange suggested that advances in computer technology could lead to a more centralized economy, overcoming the knowledge problem posed by economist Friedrich Hayek. However, the computers of the day were too primitive to achieve this.

  • Gordon Moore formulated Moore’s Law in 1965, predicting that computing power would double every 18 months. This exponential growth in processing power over subsequent decades allowed computers to store and process huge amounts of information.

  • The arrival of the internet and World Wide Web in the 1990s enabled greater connectivity and decentralized communication, inspiring many new internet-based businesses. However, many failed due to flawed business models.

  • In the 2000s, the spread of broadband and especially mobile internet led to an explosion in internet use and ushered in the Connected Revolution.

  • Four key changes have transformed business strategy: democratization of processing power, declining communication costs, ubiquitous connectivity through sensors, and increasing returns to scale from data analysis.

  • Together these changes have reduced barriers to entry, allowed decentralized network-based activities, and generated vast amounts of new data - transforming economic and social dynamics.

  • Advances in computer processing power have given individuals access to professional tools once only available to large organizations. This has empowered individuals to create value on a new scale.

  • Falling communication costs have made it easier for individuals to share value with each other. People can now collaborate on complex tasks and develop trust to facilitate exchanges.

  • Platforms like Wikipedia showed that decentralized networks of individuals can substitute for entire organizations in creating value.

  • Transactions costs dropped low enough that traditional organizational bonds started to break apart. Economies of scale collapsed in industries like newspapers.

  • Platform businesses emerged to coordinate and grow these decentralized networks. Platforms invest in infrastructure to support network growth rather than internal resources.

  • Platforms combine aspects of Coase’s firm and Hayek’s market - they are centrally planned markets.

  • Ubiquitous connectivity and sensors enable platforms to collect limitless information to coordinate large economies in real-time, overcoming Hayek’s knowledge problem.

  • Businesses can now understand and organize large amounts of data in real time, including text, audio, video, and behavioral patterns. This enables centralized coordination of economic activity at a large scale, contrary to Hayek’s objections.

  • Platforms like Google Search and Facebook are creating centralized, planned markets at massive scale, showing capitalism is compatible with centralization.

  • Platforms create entirely new networks of economic and social activity where none existed before. They correct for market failures and unlock new value.

  • Concepts like economies of scale and value chains are outdated. Platforms represent a massive, immediate shift beyond incremental change.

  • Platforms like Alibaba have enabled e-commerce and payments for remote regions of China before physical retail could reach them.

  • The shift to platforms is much bigger than just the sharing economy and will continue as more industries adopt connected technology. To understand the modern economy, you have to understand platforms.

Here is a summary of the key points in the story:

  • An entrepreneur builds expensive management software for dentists’ offices called Dentasoft. It is successful initially but then two young entrepreneurs build a cheaper, better alternative called Dent.io. Dentasoft struggles and eventually goes bankrupt.

  • The point is that software alone is a commodity with no defensibility. Competitors can always make something better or cheaper.

  • Fred Wilson of Union Square Ventures realized this and decided to invest in companies with network effects - social networks, marketplaces, etc. These have defensibility because of the value of their user base.

  • The evolution of enterprise software follows this pattern. Expensive on-premise software is disrupted by cheaper cloud-based services, which are then differentiated by building developer networks and platforms.

  • Healthcare software is evolving similarly, from expensive digital record systems to cloud services and now patient-facing telemedicine platforms.

  • Platforms have strong “moats” because of network effects. Investors love platforms because of their ability to dominate markets. Platforms are worth more than linear businesses.

  • Investors value platform businesses much more highly than linear businesses. Platforms have an average revenue multiple of 8.9x while linear businesses are valued at 2-4x revenue.

  • This valuation gap is widening over time as platforms perform better financially with faster growth, higher return on capital, and larger profit margins.

  • Platforms are projected to make up 5% of the S&P 500 by 2020 and 50% of net income in 25 years, up from just 1% in 2000.

  • The next wave of public companies is heavily weighted toward platforms, especially among unicorn startups which are valued at over $1 billion.

  • Platforms benefit from near zero marginal costs, allowing them to scale exponentially more efficiently than linear businesses that have to invest in increasing capacity.

  • As a result, platforms can run global operations with very few employees compared to linear businesses. For example, Alibaba has 35,000 employees vs Walmart with over 2 million.

  • The zero marginal cost dynamics and network effects underlying platforms are key reasons why they are valued so much higher than linear businesses by investors.

  • Platform businesses like Airbnb have a natural advantage over linear businesses like hotels because they don’t have to own assets or inventory. Their marginal cost of supply is zero once the platform is built.

  • This allows platforms to scale much more easily and cheaply than linear businesses, which have to invest capital to expand inventory and supply.

  • Platforms face a chicken-and-egg problem in the beginning, needing to attract both producers and consumers to gain critical mass. But once past this point, network effects kick in.

  • As the network grows, platforms see their costs decrease and revenues increase faster than linear businesses. Margins improve dramatically at scale.

  • Handy was able to use network effects to provide faster service than competitors by carefully choosing markets and focusing on repeat business. This helped it outlast competitors like Homejoy.

  • The network value platforms create through improving quality and exceeding expectations over time is a key advantage over linear businesses selling products/services with just inherent value.

  • Platform businesses rely on network effects - the more users they have, the more valuable the platform becomes. As a result, platforms that reach massive scale can generate huge profits with low marginal costs.

  • This winner-take-all dynamic means there is often intense competition between platforms fighting for dominance in a market. Only one or two platforms tend to prevail.

  • Alibaba battled eBay for dominance of e-commerce in China in the 2000s. Alibaba won by offering a free model and building stronger network effects, showcasing the importance of understanding local markets.

  • After beating eBay, Alibaba needed a new monetization model. It developed an advertising model similar to Google by becoming the go-to site for product searches.

  • To protect this model, Alibaba blocked other search engines like Baidu from indexing its product listings, sparking controversy but cementing Alibaba’s position.

  • As platforms like Alibaba achieve dominance, linear businesses often struggle to compete, as the winner-take-all nature of platforms squeezes their profits over time.

  • Alibaba made a strategic decision early on to block external search engines like Baidu from crawling its e-commerce sites. This forced consumers to go directly to Alibaba instead of through an intermediary like Baidu.

  • This risky move paid off by changing consumer behavior - Chinese shoppers started going directly to Alibaba instead of Baidu for product searches, helping Alibaba dominate China’s e-commerce market.

  • Platform battles are often winner-take-all. Alibaba beat eBay and Baidu to control up to 90% of China’s e-commerce. Google has over 90% of search in Europe.

  • Platforms gain dominance through network effects and creating lock-in, not by owning assets like old monopolies. Users collectively choose platforms, they aren’t forced on them.

  • Platform monopolies aren’t as entrenched as old monopolies because they succeed based on participation, not ownership. Uber enlisted its users in political battles vs regulators.

  • Platform monopolies like Uber, Facebook, and Airbnb are different from traditional monopolies because they are “monopolies of the willing”, built from grassroots user support rather than top-down control.

  • Platforms grow through network effects - by delivering more value as their networks expand, unlike traditional monopolies which profit by squeezing value from an industry. Platforms expand markets rather than dominate existing ones.

  • Platforms stimulate new economic activity, often creating new markets and opportunities rather than just capturing market share. For example, Airbnb grows without hurting hotels, and Alibaba enabled the rise of “Taobao villages”.

  • Today’s platform monopolies are highly competitive compared to old monopolies due to low barriers to entry and the ability for users to switch platforms quickly. Dominant platforms are still vulnerable to disruption by competitors.

  • Platform monopolies tend not to last as long as traditional monopolies. The speed of technological change means there are constant threats from new entrants. Microsoft’s smartphone dominance was eclipsed within a decade by Apple and Google.

  • Overall, platform monopolies can bring valuable innovations and expand markets, especially in the short-term, though risks of stagnation emerge over time without competition. But the competitive dynamics of platforms make their monopolies less durable than traditional monopolies.

  • Platform businesses create value differently than traditional linear businesses. Rather than owning the means of production, they own the means of connection - facilitating transactions between producers and consumers.

  • The core transaction is the key activity that enables these exchanges on a platform. It is the process that allows producers and consumers to repeatedly exchange value. Designing an effective core transaction is critical.

  • Traditional business tools like Porter’s value chain don’t fully apply to platforms. Platforms have a value ecosystem, with the core transaction as the primary activity and other support functions enabling it.

  • Examples like Uber and YouTube illustrate core transactions. For Uber it is drivers making themselves available and riders requesting rides. For YouTube it is uploading and viewing videos.

  • Getting the core transaction right explains successes like Tinder, where the double opt-in creates valuable matches. Poor core transaction design explains failures like Airtime.

  • The key is to focus on facilitating valuable exchanges, not just accumulating users. Repeated exchanges drive the growth and sustainability of a platform.

  • The core transaction is the repeatable set of actions that producers and consumers take to create and consume value on a platform. It has four steps:

  1. Create - Producers create inventory or value to be consumed through the platform. This is the raw material for transactions.

  2. Connect - One side initiates the transaction by connecting with the other party.

  3. Consume - Consumers extract value from the inventory on the platform.

  4. Compensate - Consumers reward producers, often through payment but also via reviews, likes, etc.

  • These four steps function like an assembly line to manufacture transactions and value. However, unlike a factory, a platform doesn’t directly control the inventory creation step.

  • Platforms aim to optimize the efficiency of the core transaction, but can’t dictate inventory creation. They must incentivize producers.

  • The two sides are interdependent, so optimizing one side affects the other. Platforms must balance both.

  • Non-monetary compensation like reviews helps maintain producer quality and fuels future transactions by storing value in the platform.

  • Linear businesses and platform businesses have different priorities - efficiency versus quality. Trade-offs exist with any changes.

  • Both aim to create a repeatable process that provides value. This requires efficient, high-quality throughput at each step.

  • The core transaction differs between exchange platforms (two-way) and maker platforms (one-way).

  • Getting the core transaction right is critical, as seen with Tinder’s success facilitating dating matches.

  • Platform startups often mistakenly try to build multiple core transactions from the start. Focus on one transaction first.

  • Successful platforms like LinkedIn, Uber, and Facebook started simple with just one transaction before expanding. Simplicity enables growth.

  • Finding product-market fit with one core transaction is key before attempting more. Dominance in one area is better than smaller penetration in many.

  • Platforms need to perform four core functions: audience building, matchmaking, providing core tools/services, and creating rules/standards. These support the core transaction.

  • Audience building involves attracting both producers and consumers to create a liquid marketplace. Uber uses controversial practices like surge pricing to balance driver supply and rider demand.

  • Matchmaking connects the right producers and consumers to enable transactions. Airbnb improved its matchmaking algorithm to recommend listings based on user preferences.

  • Core tools and services support the transaction by lowering costs, removing barriers, and providing data. Amazon offers fulfillment services to help sellers scale.

  • Rules and standards govern allowed and forbidden behaviors on the platform. Reddit relies on community moderators to enforce standards of content and behavior.

  • These four functions create the “visible hand” that facilitates transactions and interactions in a platform’s network. They turn the platform’s community into a marketplace.

  • Ricing (rapidly increasing growth in communities) can help create balanced growth for a platform. Uber used aggressive tactics to acquire drivers and grow its network.

  • Airbnb also used controversial growth tactics early on, including spamming Craigslist posters to divert users to Airbnb’s site. Airbnb capitalized on the 2008 Democratic National Convention’s lodging shortage in Denver to gain national exposure.

  • PayPal built a “charity robot” to place bids on eBay using PayPal, to introduce eBay sellers to its payment platform.

  • Platforms often use aggressive or controversial tactics in their early stages to build liquidity, which is critical for creating network effects. Once a platform has lots of users, matchmaking them efficiently becomes important to facilitating transactions and creating value.

  • Matchmaking systems use data to identify the key product characteristics that will appeal to different user groups. Platforms then build algorithms and tools to efficiently connect users based on this data.

  • Uber’s automatic matching algorithm is like solving a traveling salesman problem to efficiently route drivers to riders. Effective matching is critical for platforms like Uber to retain drivers.

  • Amazon uses collaborative filtering to connect users with relevant products, like its “Customers who bought this also bought” recommendations.

  • YouTube switched from optimizing for clicks to watch time in order to better match viewers with engaging content.

  • Platforms like Twitter set rules and standards to manage large communities of users. Some are explicit rules set by the company, others are implicit norms enforced by the community.

  • Twitter’s 140-character limit on tweets originated from SMS text message constraints but became part of the platform’s identity. Short tweets were easy to create and consume and differentiated Twitter from other platforms.

  • Twitter has many rules governing content like spam, impersonation, etc to manage the community. These rules evolve over time as the platform changes.

  • Early on, Twitter took a hands-off approach with developers building clients and accessing its API. This helped Twitter grow but meant it had little control over the user experience.

  • As Twitter grew, it exerted more control - buying a popular 3rd party client, releasing official mobile apps, and restricting API access to control the core experience and monetize.

  • Twitter shifted to allow developers to build complementary businesses on top of the platform rather than alternative clients that would own the core experience.

  • Balancing producers, consumers and the platform is key but Twitter made tough decisions to scale and monetize by controlling the core user experience.

  • Governing a platform and setting effective rules is challenging. Platforms like Twitter can struggle with unintended consequences if rules are not well designed.

  • Twitter has faced challenges due to unclear identity, rampant abuse/harassment, and poor user engagement. It has not effectively governed its community.

  • Methods like algorithms, editorial control, and reputation systems can help platforms govern users, but all have limitations. Reputation systems in particular can be gamed and lack context.

  • The most effective platforms use a balanced combination of these methods to monitor behavior and build user trust. Rules should incentivize good behavior and discourage bad behavior.

  • If users don’t trust a platform due to poor governance, it’s a bad sign. Twitter has struggled to build this second-order platform trust recently.

  • Platforms need to provide core tools and services to facilitate the core transaction between users. These should focus on enabling the key steps of the transaction - creation, consumption, matching, and transfer.

  • Tools should be decentralized and self-service, like YouTube’s video uploading or Uber’s driver navigation. Services are more centralized, like customer support.

  • Tools and services should directly support the core transaction. Extra “too useful” features overcomplicate the platform. Simplicity and efficiency are key.

  • For platforms with high transaction risk like Uber or Airbnb, additional services are needed to build trust and prevent harm, since parts of the transaction happen offline. This is because negative experiences will still reflect poorly on the platform, even if they don’t happen on it directly.

  • To keep users safe, platforms need to prevent bad actors from getting on in the first place. Common methods include collecting personal information for screening and doing background checks.

  • However, with large networks some bad actors will inevitably slip through. Platforms need to respond quickly to incidents and have insurance and support systems in place.

  • Uber and Airbnb have both dealt with safety issues. They’ve increased insurance coverage, improved background checks, and invested more in customer service and safety teams.

  • A platform’s value ecosystem needs to continuously adapt as the network grows. Successful platforms start with a single core transaction then add secondary transactions once the network is large enough.

  • All four platform functions (audience building, matchmaking, providing core tools and services, and setting rules and standards) must evolve as the network expands into new transaction types. Designing a platform is an ongoing process of sociological insight and behavior design, not a one-time industrial design effort.

  • Chatroulette was an online platform that connected random users via webcam for brief video chats. It grew extremely quickly and became a viral sensation, but then traffic dried up just as fast.

  • The problem was the poor quality of users as Chatroulette scaled. A large percentage of users acted inappropriately or indecently, scaring away most normal users. This highlights the importance of nurturing a high-quality user base as a platform grows.

  • Platforms need effective governance, especially around inappropriate content. Chatroulette failed to moderate user behavior, leading to its downfall.

  • Sequencing which types of users join a platform is important. Had Chatroulette focused first on onboarding more women or limiting initial users, it may have cultivated a better community.

  • Overall, the Chatroulette story demonstrates the need for platforms to carefully curate their user base and establish governance early on as they scale, in order to prevent the network effects from harming the platform. The quality of a platform’s community trumps merely having quantity of users.

  • Chatroulette was anonymous and had no registration, making it difficult to police users. This led to it deteriorating as more inappropriate users joined.

  • Friendster was one of the first social networks but struggled to manage its growth. It had scaling issues and fake profiles became a problem.

  • Myspace took a hands-off approach and allowed fake profiles and anonymous users. This attracted child predators and spam, damaging its reputation.

  • Facebook was very deliberate about its growth. It launched only for Harvard students with .edu emails and real names. This helped it avoid many of the problems faced by earlier social networks.

  • Facebook started at Harvard and strategically expanded to other Ivy League schools where students already had social connections. This allowed cross-campus “friending” which drove growth.

  • Facebook used a “surround strategy” to expand to other colleges - opening at nearby schools to create demand at the target school. This allowed it to overtake competitors.

  • Facebook resisted opening up too fast, waiting until around 20% of a school’s students were demanding access before opening there. This ensured strong initial usage.

  • Facebook carefully added high school students, requiring invites to maintain quality and real identities. This slower growth protected the network.

  • Traditional network effect theory assumes all users are equally valuable. But most network effects are local - you benefit more from people close to you joining.

  • Facebook’s thoughtful growth strategy focused on high-quality local network effects, not just rapid global growth. This allowed it to scale massively while maintaining a useful network.

  • Network effects are typically local, not global. The value to you of new users depends on how closely connected they are to you in the network.

  • A small, dense network is often more valuable than a larger, dispersed one because it enables more transactions between users. Platforms often start in a niche to build density before expanding.

  • Myspace focused on rapid growth without coherence, creating a large network without localized value. Facebook and others succeeded by starting in a dense niche.

  • Google’s social networks like Orkut and Google+ attracted many users but failed to get them to interact, creating ghost towns without localized network effects.

  • Negative network effects can also occur when bad users detract value, as happened on Chatroulette. This demonstrates network effects aren’t uniformly positive.

  • Overall, network effects are more complex and localized than simply “the more users the better.” First-mover advantage is not as definitive as some assume. Later entrants can succeed by starting locally and densifying.

  • Reverse network effects occur when bad users drive away good users and harm the network. Examples include trolls, spammers, predators, and fake profiles.

  • First-mover advantage is not enough - growth at any cost can backfire if it brings in low-quality users. Friendster and MySpace grew quickly but collapsed due to reverse network effects.

  • Platforms must focus on sustainable, high-quality growth that creates value for users. Not all growth is good.

  • Software features are less important than the network itself and the community of users. Users define the platform.

  • Growth is path dependent - the initial users shape a platform’s identity and future trajectory. Facebook was thoughtful about cultivating its community from the start.

  • Platforms have the most leverage to shape their community when just getting started. After a reputation forms, it’s very hard to change.

  • Facebook was intentional about creating a “culture of real identity” early on, requiring users to sign up with their real names and .edu emails. This helped establish Facebook as a place for authentic connections compared to MySpace’s “anything goes” culture.

  • Facebook focused on growing slowly at first, college by college, to ensure the platform was ready to scale. This allowed it to optimize features and build community culture before expanding more broadly.

  • Not all users are equally valuable to a platform. Celebrities and other high-value users can act as magnets to attract more users. Platforms often target these users early on through exclusivity or incentives.

  • The sequence in which users join a platform matters due to path dependence. Starting with high-quality users can help seed platforms with valuable content and set community norms.

  • The “network effects ladder” is a framework for systematically growing network quality. It involves moving through stages of connecting users, enabling communication, collaboration, curation, and community.

Here are the key points about why platforms fail and how to avoid it:

  • Platforms often fail because they don’t create enough value and engagement for their users. The network effects don’t take off.

  • To avoid failure, platforms need to nail the core transaction and really understand the key jobs, pains, and gains for each side of their market. Solve a real problem that users care about.

  • Getting the initial launch and seeding strategy right is crucial - platforms need enough initial content and users to reach critical mass. Poor initial seeding is a common reason for failure.

  • Platforms should focus on activating both sides of their market, not just growth at any cost. Two-sided activity metrics are key.

  • They should climb the network effects ladder - going beyond just connections to enable communication, compensation, curation, collaboration and community. Stronger network effects make failure less likely.

  • Spectacular platform failures often occur when founders ignore early warning signs and lose focus on the value proposition. Avoiding failure requires knowing what metrics really matter.

  • Platforms should remain laser focused on solving the core transaction and resist feature creep or trying to be all things to all users. Stick to the core value proposition.

  • Color, a photo-sharing startup, raised $41 million in 2011 based on its proximity technology that would allow people to instantly share photos and videos with others nearby.

  • The app launched after SXSW to great hype, quickly rising to #2 in the App Store.

  • But the app failed because it only worked if many people around you were also using it, which was not the case for most users. It became a “ghost town”.

  • This “chicken and egg” problem of needing users on both sides for a platform to work is common. Uber faced it too.

  • Reaching critical mass, where enough users join to make the platform valuable, is key to overcoming this.

  • Platforms use subsidies like referral fees, lowered prices, and special features to incentivize users to join before critical mass. This builds the initial liquidity needed.

  • Once critical mass is reached, platforms can take off rapidly due to network effects. But building that initial liquidity is very challenging.

  • Companies can use monetary subsidies like large upfront investments (e.g. Microsoft and the Xbox) or cooperating with industry incumbents (e.g. Google and the Open Handset Alliance) to attract producers to their new platforms.

  • They can use product features like acting as a producer themselves to bootstrap initial content (e.g. Quora, Reddit) or tapping into existing networks to siphon off some users (e.g. Airbnb tapping Craigslist).

  • Platforms can attract high-value “celebrity” users through special features or monetary incentives, knowing these users will then attract others (e.g. Twitter’s verified accounts).

  • Overall, platforms need to combine monetary subsidies, useful product features, and deliberate user sequencing in creative ways to solve the chicken-and-egg problem and reach critical mass. The seven strategies highlighted offer proven techniques to do this.

  • Yelp created an “Elite Squad” of top reviewers to incentivize high-quality content. Being in the squad comes with special benefits and status. This helped Yelp quickly build a strong community.

  • Etsy focused on crafters who were both buyers and sellers on the platform. Targeting this group allowed Etsy to fill both sides of the marketplace early on.

  • Platforms like Instagram and OpenTable provided single-user utility at first, so users saw value even before the network effects kicked in.

  • Other strategies include targeting influencers, building for a niche target audience, and providing direct payments to attract initial users.

  • The goal of these strategies is to overcome the “chicken and egg” problem platforms face in attracting their first users and balancing both sides of the market. Once initial traction is achieved, network effects can take over.

  • Airbnb has spawned many services to support hosts, such as professional photographers, listing writers, dynamic pricing tools, key management, and check-in services.

  • Uber has also led to derivative businesses like car leasing for drivers, specialized rideshare insurance, and financing for vehicles.

  • This phenomenon of complementary businesses benefiting from platforms is not new - SEO experts and social media managers grew around Google and social media, app developers around iOS and Android, etc.

  • Investors see opportunities in these derivative businesses, but they also face risks if platforms limit access or expand into their territory.

  • Zynga provides a cautionary tale, as it grew quickly by spamming Facebook users to play its games like FarmVille, but then struggled when Facebook tightened its policies. Its overreliance on Facebook proved risky.

  • Zynga and Twitter both built businesses around dominant platforms (Facebook and Twitter itself), but struggled when those platforms tightened control.

  • Early Android phone makers like HTC and Motorola initially succeeded but were later crushed by Samsung.

  • Samsung then dominated the Android phone market, but has since lost share to Apple and low-cost Chinese competitors.

  • The evolution of the smartphone market demonstrates how platforms like iOS and Android now sit at the top of the pyramid, with huge power and sustainable competitive advantage.

  • Linear businesses like Samsung can still succeed, but struggle to maintain an edge as competitors quickly copy their features. Platforms are harder to emulate.

  • Samsung has tried but struggled to transition into more of a platform business itself. Decline of its core phone business seems likely to continue.

  • In the current economic landscape, platforms offer the biggest opportunities. But you can’t just copy existing platforms - you need to identify where new platform opportunities will emerge.

  • New platforms often operate in legal gray areas, drawing scrutiny from incumbents. Airbnb and Uber are prominent examples of battles between platforms and regulators.

  • Platform companies like Airbnb, Uber, eBay, YouTube, and Lending Club have faced major legal and regulatory obstacles as they disrupted established industries.

  • These legal issues often center around who is liable for harm caused on the platforms. Platforms argue they are just connectors and not responsible, while consumers and regulators disagree.

  • Uber faces lawsuits about classifying drivers as contractors rather than employees, which limits benefits and Uber’s costs. If Uber loses, it could owe hundreds of millions in damages.

  • Airbnb faces regulations meant for hotels that it does not comply with, like safety standards. Cities like New York have tried cracking down.

  • Overcoming legal hurdles is common for platforms. It gives them upside if they succeed, but they risk being driven out of business if they fail.

  • Workers have valid concerns about their treatment and lack of benefits in the “gig economy.” Changes to social safety nets may be needed to account for this new labor model.

  • The future likely involves dominant platforms in each sector, with examples like Alibaba in China consolidating many services.

Here are the key points from the passage:

  • Tencent has outperformed Alibaba in terms of profits and revenue, despite Alibaba getting more attention after its IPO.

  • Tencent makes most of its revenue from virtual goods sold on its platforms QQ and WeChat, as well as from games.

  • WeChat started as a messaging app but has expanded into an über-platform that supports mini-apps, payments, and more.

  • Tencent’s success with WeChat has led some to predict a similar platform will emerge in the U.S., but replicating WeChat will be challenging due to Apple and Google’s dominance.

  • Rather than one “superplatform”, it’s more likely that separate platform ecosystems will develop around major tech companies like Google, Apple, Facebook, and Amazon.

  • In China, the main platform ecosystems are controlled by Baidu, Alibaba, and Tencent (BAT), which each operate multiple overlapping and competing platforms.

  • Alibaba and Tencent are the two dominant tech companies in China. They compete across multiple industries, including ecommerce, messaging, gaming, video streaming, and more.

  • Each company has its own strengths - Alibaba in ecommerce, Tencent in messaging and gaming. But they compete fiercely across all areas.

  • For example, after Alibaba acquired Youku Tudou (a video platform), Tencent invested heavily in JD.com to compete with Alibaba in ecommerce.

  • Similarly, Alibaba created a messaging app Laiwang to compete with WeChat, and each company has its own app store.

  • The result is rival platform ecosystems, like in the US with Apple, Google, Facebook etc. Competition happens across industries between incompatible platforms.

  • The author provides tips to spot potential platform opportunities:

  1. Look for technologies that reduce transaction costs and remove gatekeepers.

  2. Identify implicit or underserved networks and build platforms on top.

  3. Find large, fragmented sources of supply that can be aggregated through a platform.

In summary, Alibaba and Tencent demonstrate intense cross-industry competition between platforms in China. The author suggests ways to identify opportunities for new platform businesses.

  • Many B2B online marketplaces launched in the late 1990s/early 2000s but failed because they couldn’t attract suppliers. Suppliers worried about price competition and already had established sales channels.

  • Alibaba succeeded where others failed by targeting small/medium businesses in China. It gave them access to global markets.

  • Uber also succeeded by leveraging fragmented supply (drivers) and making it easier for passengers to get rides.

  • ClassPass is another example that aggregated fragmented local fitness options into one platform.

  • There are still opportunities in healthcare for platforms that connect doctors and patients in new ways and reduce inefficiency.

  • The Internet of Things has potential but needs a platform to coordinate all the devices and overcome fragmentation. Apple, Google, and Uber are making big moves here.

  • Overall, look for technologies that reduce transaction costs, implicit/underserved networks, and large fragmented supply sources. Timing also matters when identifying platform opportunities.

Here are the key points about the business model and impact of platforms:

  • Platforms like Uber and Airbnb have built their business models around not owning significant physical assets. This allows them to be more nimble and avoid liabilities associated with asset ownership.

  • The Internet of Things and industrial platforms have enormous potential to drive efficiency gains. However, the value will likely accrue to the platforms connecting the devices rather than the device makers themselves.

  • Financial platforms like AngelList, LendingClub, and Bitcoin are opening up investment opportunities and financial services to new groups of consumers.

  • Bitcoin’s underlying blockchain technology allows digital transactions without relying on a central authority. However, Bitcoin itself still faces governance challenges. The blockchain is powerful but still requires platform companies to build services on top.

  • Overall, platforms are transforming industries but will remain the dominant business model. The blockchain enables decentralized infrastructure but won’t undo the need for platforms.

  • Platforms are transforming major industries like healthcare, the Internet of Things, and finance. Bitcoin and the blockchain are enabling new financial applications and threatening to disrupt traditional financial institutions.

  • In healthcare, platforms like Apple HealthKit are centralizing and improving access to health data. New IoT platforms will connect home devices and allow centralized control.

  • Bitcoin’s decentralized blockchain technology enables developers to build new financial applications and reduces transaction costs. Major banks are investing in Bitcoin and blockchain startups.

  • These sectors will likely see significant turbulence and disruption from new platforms and technologies. There are still regulatory risks, but the opportunities for innovation are enormous.

  • The authors provide free resources to apply platform concepts to your business, including a platform ecosystem diagram, a platform business model canvas, and a glossary of key terms.

  • The authors thank the Applico team for their contributions, especially Greg Battle, Nathaniel Malka, and Erik Zambrano.

  • They thank the entrepreneurs they interviewed for sharing insights.

  • Glen Weyl provided valuable perspective on platform economics.

  • The team at St. Martin’s Press, especially editor Emily Carleton, helped shape and publish the book.

  • Agent William Clark supported the project from the start.

  • Alex thanks his mother for her unconditional love, work ethic and setting an example. His sister Christina motivated him. Will Roush and George Hornig believed in Alex early on.

  • Nicholas thanks his parents for their support during the writing process. His sister Natalie inspires him to do better. Eric Weiner mentored Nicholas and helped shape the book.

  • The book represents a collaborative effort and the authors are grateful to all who contributed.

  • The author thanks various people for their help with research, providing information, keeping him focused, and overall support in writing the book.

  • Some links referenced may no longer be active.

  • Uncited quotes come from interviews the authors conducted or direct conversations.

  • In the Prologue, there are quotes and facts about the decline of Nokia and Blackberry as their mobile platforms were overtaken by iOS and Android.

  • Chapter 1 explains how platforms like Facebook, Google, and Alibaba have come to dominate the internet. It discusses platform economics using eBay, GitHub, and Red Hat as examples.

  • Chapter 2 contrasts Friedrich Hayek’s theories of distributed economic coordination with centralized optimization through big data, using Alibaba and Facebook as examples.

  • Chapter 3 introduces the idea of zero marginal cost enabled by platforms like YouTube, with an example about dental practice software.

  • There are notes on sources for quotes and facts provided throughout the summary.

Here is a summary of the key points from the book Platform Revolution by Geoffrey Parker, Marshall Van Alstyne, and Sangeet Choudary:

  • Platforms like Uber, Airbnb, and Facebook are transforming the global economy by enabling peer-to-peer exchange on a massive scale. They leverage technology to facilitate interactions between producers and consumers.

  • Successful platforms follow key strategic principles like designing for interaction effects, reducing transaction costs, building trust and reputation systems, and managing disruptive growth.

  • Platforms often start niche, with a focused user base, before expanding into wider markets. Their growth frequently disrupts traditional industries like taxis and hotels.

  • Platforms benefit from network effects - their value grows exponentially as more users join. This can lead to winner-take-most dynamics and monopolies.

  • Platforms create value by establishing rules, tools, and standards that reduce transaction friction and build trust. But they also need flexibility to allow organic growth.

  • The book profiles many leading platforms like Airbnb, Amazon, and Alibaba. It analyzes their strategies and business models using examples and data.

  • Overall, the authors argue platforms are reshaping the global economy and will drive much innovation and change in coming years through their network-driven business models.

Here is a summary of the key points from the passages:

  • Passage 6 discusses the rapid growth of Uber, demonstrating how mobile apps can enable new platform businesses.

  • Passage 7 provides statistics on YouTube’s massive user base and shift to prioritizing watch time over views.

  • Passage 8 quotes YouTube executives on the decision to focus on watch time rather than just views.

  • Passage 9 features a YouTube executive further explaining the rationale behind the watch time focus.

  • Passage 10 gives statistics on Twitter’s user base growth.

  • Passage 11 discusses Facebook’s beginnings and growth at Harvard.

  • Passage 12 describes Twitter opening up its platform to outside developers.

  • Passage 13 quotes an investor on Twitter’s platform potential.

  • Passage 14 covers Twitter restricting API access to control the user experience.

  • Passage 15 features a Twitter executive discussing the API clampdown.

  • Passage 16 provides statistics on Twitter’s user retention challenges.

  • Passage 17 discusses dynamics among Twitter’s founders.

  • Passage 18 argues Twitter succeeded by facilitating communication, not constraining it.

  • Passage 19 notes Twitter’s challenges handling harassment issues.

  • Passage 20 gives an overview of early employees at top tech companies.

  • Passages 21-23 examine Airbnb’s growth, use of background checks, and fraud challenges.

  • Passage 24 compares Airbnb’s risks to hiring risks for any business.

  • Passage 25 discusses Airbnb’s fraud response team.

  • Passages 26-27 cover dysfunction and infighting among Twitter’s founders.

  • Passage 28 summarizes the book’s platform modeling process.

Here are the key points from Zuckerberg’s interviews at Y Combinator’s Startup School from 2009 to 2013:

  • In 2009, Zuckerberg discussed Facebook’s founding and early growth strategies. He emphasized the importance of building a service people want to use and getting users before worrying about revenue.

  • In 2010, he gave advice on company culture, saying founders should only hire people they would work for themselves. He recommended setting up processes early but being flexible as things change.

  • In 2011, Zuckerberg talked about Facebook’s expansion beyond college students to the broader public. He discussed balancing user growth with engagement.

  • In 2012, he covered Facebook going public. He said the IPO enabled long-term focus and made it easier to recruit employees. He advised entrepreneurs to focus on problems they care about.

  • In 2013, Zuckerberg discussed mobile strategy. He explained Facebook’s transition to prioritizing mobile, through developing standalone apps and acquiring companies like Instagram. He encouraged startups to adopt mobile early.

Overall, he covered Facebook’s origins, early priorities, culture, transition to public company, and mobile-first strategy. His advice emphasized focusing on users over revenue initially, building a strong team culture, staying flexible, and getting on mobile ASAP.

Here is a summary of the key points from the excerpt of ckVC/status/665212984445296640:

  • Rothman was speaking at a conference called “Next Economy: What’s the Future of Work?“.

  • His talk focused on how the internet and technology are transforming the nature of work and the economy.

  • He discussed how digital platforms like Uber are creating new types of work and flexible earning opportunities.

  • However, he also acknowledged concerns about the stability and security of platform-based work.

  • Overall, Rothman explored how digital platforms are disrupting traditional notions of work, careers, and the social safety net. His talk highlighted both the potential benefits and challenges of this economic shift.

Here is a summary of the key points from the specified pages:

  • Economies of scale are important for linear businesses like manufacturing, but platforms benefit from network effects.

  • Ecosystems involve competition, but platforms create value through open ecosystems.

  • Efficiency is a key goal in business, but too much focus on efficiency can be counterproductive.

  • Platforms like Facebook succeeded by leveraging network effects, not just improving efficiency.

  • Market power of platforms can be abused, so some government regulation is appropriate.

  • Platforms expand markets and opportunity, though winners still take most of the value.

  • Matchmaking platforms like Twitter need good rules and standards to prevent unintended consequences.

  • Core interaction must create real value for users for platforms like Uber to succeed.

  • User sequencing and attracting pivotal users is key for growth of platforms.

  • Competing platforms can drive innovation but also create instability in ecosystems.

  • Decline of platforms like Nokia shows the speed of change in tech; terminal decline is difficult to recover from.

Here are the key points from the book Modern Monopolies:

  • Platforms like Uber, Airbnb, and Facebook are dominating the 21st century economy through network effects, economies of scale, and winner-take-all dynamics.

  • Platforms follow Hayek’s distributed model rather than a centralized model, leveraging information spread across network participants.

  • Successful platforms focus on the core transaction at their heart (e.g. rides for Uber) and get that right before expanding.

  • Platforms utilize pricing, matching, branding, and other mechanisms to facilitate valuable transactions and subsidize participation.

  • Network effects, asset leverage, and zero marginal costs help platforms scale rapidly as they reduce barriers for users and suppliers.

  • Poor governance and misaligned incentives can cause platforms to fail if they don’t maintain trust and value among participants.

  • Finding and improving upon the core transaction is key to creating and scaling a successful platform business.

In summary, the book examines how platforms utilize economic concepts like network effects and transaction costs to connect users and suppliers and achieve monopolistic dominance. The insights can help spot and build the next generation of platform businesses.

#book-summary
Author Photo

About Matheus Puppe